The role of DR in ensuring a resilient and sustainable energy system increases considerably with a higher share of RES stepping in the energy mix of regions. In general, RES are characterized with more frequent energy market price fluctuations due to a mismatch between uncontrollable weather-dependent generation and currently relatively inflexible energy consumption. Shifting the energy consumption from high-price hours to lower price hours not only helps to avoid extra costs to the entire economy, but also ensures the possibility to minimize fossil-based energy generation, therefore contributing to the achievement of ambitious zero-emission goals.
2. The Nature of Demand-Side Management and Demand Response
Before diving into the layers of DR performance influencers and the coherence of their relationships, it is crucial to investigate the main characteristics and components of DSM and DR.
2.1. The Evolution of Demand-Side Management
In the late 1970s, the concept of DSM was introduced in Europe and the US with the main drivers being changes in the electricity grid, electrification progress, industrial development, technological evolution, increasing loads and the ageing of the existing electricity system
[4]. Gellings and Chamberlin can be considered as the forerunners in DSM research, who primarily defined DSM as the planning and implementation of activities aimed at influencing consumers’ electricity consumption, resulting in a change in the utility’s load shape, i.e., a change in the time pattern and volume of the utility’s load
[5][6][7][8]. In 1993, Gellings and Chamberlin refined the previous definition of DSM, emphasizing the inclusion of activities commonly referred to as load management, electrification, strategic growth or intentional market share gains
[9].
In the 1970s and most of the 1990s, DSM was implemented by vertically integrated utilities in a structured and regulated environment. This began to change in the late 1980s and early 1990s, when the energy sector entered a process of restructuring and liberalizing energy markets, which was extensively studied by Joskow, as well as by Beesley–Littlechild
[10][11][12][13]. The move away from standardized cost-of-service principles allowed electricity producers to sell electricity at market prices based on supply and demand interaction. At the same time, the restructuring process shifted responsibility for grid maintenance from the electricity utilities to the system operators, which reduced the incentive for traditional utilities to maintain demand management programs
[13][14].
During the 1990s, the problems of climate change accelerated the evolution of energy efficiency and renewable energy in such a way that it emphasized the need for a flexible energy system, as well as a broadened and strengthened concept of DSM and DR. In 2000, the U.S. Department of Energy highlighted that DSM programs consist of electric service planning, implementation, and monitoring activities designed to encourage consumers to change their level and pattern of electricity consumption
[15]. In 2010, Greening provided a relatively broad definition, emphasizing the changes in consumer electricity consumption in response to price, and the introduction of more energy-efficient technologies
[16]. Eissa, based on the research of Isaksen et al., Ashok and Banerjee, and Effler et al., discussed load management and characterized it as the process of scheduling loads to reduce electricity consumption and/or peak demand, which can be achieved through load shedding and restoration, load shifting, installation of energy efficient processes and equipment, usage of energy storage, cogeneration and non-conventional energy sources, as well as reactive power control
[17]. In 2011, the phenomenon of DSM was also explained by Kerr–Lemaire–Owen who added customer encouragement to modify patterns of electricity usage
[18]. In 2015, the definition proposed by Warren reflects the aforementioned explanations and also includes the vector of energy policy towards the reduction of GHG emissions, the wider use of renewable energy sources, and maintaining the safe operation of the energy system
[19].
According to the type of implementation, DSM is usually divided into two main categories: energy efficiency and DR (
Figure 1)
[14][17][20][21][22]. However, some authors, for instance, Stanelyte et al., based on Warren, also highlighted on-site back-up (storage, generation) as a separate category of DSM
[4]. Strategic load growth was singled out separately in Lampropoulos et al.’s research
[23], while Akbari–Dibavar et al., in addition to DR and energy efficiency, identified the following DSM categories: load growth, energy saving, demand shifting, spinning reserve, and virtual power plants
[24].
Figure 1. Classifications of DSM and DR, based on the scope on the research.
The main characteristics of energy efficiency, which are common in the reviewed publications, are its orientation towards reduction of energy consumption by using energy-efficient technologies and equipment without diminishing comfort level, and its static nature, i.e., non-adaption to the signals of the energy system or the market
[21][25][26][27][28]. Maintaining comfort level is a key aspect that distinguishes energy efficiency from energy saving. Moreover, energy efficiency measures are long-term oriented.
As part of the research project, the expert working group of the World Energy Council (WEC) have evaluated several energy policy transition scenarios up to 2050, such as Bloomberg, IPCC, IEA, IRENA, BP, McKinsey, DNV, Shell, OECD, Equinor and others. Despite different assumptions based on different methodologies and technological focuses, it can be seen that all of them, notwithstanding the positive trend of economic development and, consequently, the more intensive use of energy-intensive equipment and processes, predict a significant reduction in GHG emissions. The increasing energy demand is compensated by significant energy efficiency measures
[1].
The research concludes that the main drivers of energy transition highlight electrification, decarbonization and energy efficiency. A large number of scenarios show the freedom of choice possibilities of each country’s energy system from the point of view of technology use. At the same time, when creating a balanced solution to the energy trilemma (energy affordability, security and sustainability), it is essential to take into account the peculiarities of each country, which determine the cost and safety parameters of the relevant renewable energy technology in the specific energy system. None of the scenarios believe that it is possible to achieve the ambitious net-zero aims, thus continuing the “business as usual” approach. DR and connectivity, together with storages, carbon pricing and digitalization, are the new strong indispensable players to succeed
[29].
2.2. Demand Response Products and Services
DR is a more flexible tool compared to energy efficiency. In 2006, the U.S. Department of Energy defined electricity DR as “changes in electric use by demand-side resources from their normal consumption patterns in response to changes in the price of electricity, or to incentive payments designed to induce lower electricity use at times of high wholesale market prices or when system reliability is jeopardized
[26]”. This definition was also supported by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission in 2010
[30]. In 2007, Albadi and El-Saadany emphasized that DR includes all intentional changes in end-users’ electricity consumption patterns, which aim to change the timing, instantaneous demand level, or total electricity consumption
[31]. In 2022, Morales–Espana et. al., as well as the International Energy Agency in the report on DR, provided its general explanation as shifting or reducing electricity demand with the aim of balancing the grid, and ensuring flexibility in wholesale and other electricity markets
[21][32].
DR is a mechanism that responds to price and system signals, which can be implemented at different end-user scales and at different grid levels (system transmission, distribution, retail). DR has dynamic and event-driven nature and typically involves dynamic electricity pricing, contractual or voluntary curtailment. According to Bakr’s research, DR services can be classified differently depending on certain criteria. On the one hand, is to categorize by economic or market signals (e.g., high prices) and physical emergency signals (i.e., grid signals), whereas on the other hand, it is possible to classify the DR based on the services offered (e.g., power or ancillary services). DR programs can also be categorized based on the goals of program administrators (e.g., load shaping and congestion management) or based on the compensation they offer to program members (e.g., discounts, cheaper fares)
[25]. One of the most common DR classifications is based on its stimulus or incentives. In this regard, DR can be (
Figure 1):
-
An implicit or price-based scheme in which the same time is self-dispatched or a load is controlled indirectly. Electricity consumers change or reallocate their consumption reflecting electricity price or cost signals. Electricity suppliers offer different pricing products that depend on time, for example, day and night prices or dynamic pricing based on wholesale market prices. As this is an indirect load control scheme, there is no two-way communication between consumers and operators, except a response of aggregated consumers, which can be measured by operators. Consumers make decisions individually, and in order to make them more efficient, smart metering and home energy management systems are required. The main purpose of these programs is to smooth the demand curve by offering a high price during peak periods and lower prices during off-peak periods
[18][21][22][33][34][35][36].
-
An explicit or incentive-based scheme, in which dispatchment is conducted by a third party classified as any of the following: transmission system operators, distribution system operators, or the utility or retailer of the energy user and a DR aggregator. An explicit DR scheme consists of direct load control and market-based mechanisms, which allow the trading of the participant’s dispatchable flexibility in energy markets. This DR case is based on two-way communication and agreements, which lowers the risk of response unpredictability but may affect the consumer’s independent decision and comfort level. Usually the incentive-based schemes are implemented by an aggregator
[21][22][33][34][35][36].
Usually, when the end-users obtain the possibility to participate in explicit DR, they implement it through their supplier, who acts as an aggregator. The availability of independent aggregation—a compensation mechanism, the existence of flexible markets at the DSO level, accessible minimum bids, etc.—is determined by regulatory, technical and market factors. Figure 2 represents the development steps of small end-users from having explicit DR available to them to having at least primary legislation on independent aggregators, and finally to having independent aggregators of small end-users operating in the market (Figure 2).
Figure 2. Status of explicit DR and independent aggregators across the EU Member States in 2021
[37].
In 2021, the aggregation of end-users and their participation, at least at some level, is legally allowed and technically possible in 22 EU countries, although the availability of service is not equal to the actor’s activity in the market. However, the status of Independent Aggregators can be defined as a spectrum rather than a clear category, because the range of services and multitude of markets vary from one Member State to another at different levels of maturity.
Based on that, in 2021 there were only seven EU countries where independent aggregators of end-users exist and participate in at least one electricity market: Belgium, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, as well as Hungary and Romania, where the market was just emerging. Across the abovementioned countries, only in France do independent aggregators of end-users have access to all markets. Meanwhile, in Denmark, the high level of taxes makes the business case difficult for the independent aggregators. The DR development progress during the past five years has been the most remarkable in Croatia, Hungary and Estonia. The middle part between Austria and Sweden is extremely diverse and includes countries where end-users can aggregate through a comprehensive legal framework, but the market does not reflect the range of possibilities, as well as countries where aggregation of end-users is possible through their supplier, and countries where there are locally developed entities through which end-users can participate in the markets (
Figure 3)
[37].
Figure 3. Degrees of market representation for explicit DR across EU Member states in 2021
[37].
3. The Influencers of Demand Response Implementation and Performance
DR is a complex system and consists of many various players: service providers, schemes participants, policy makers, regulators, authorities, etc. Meanwhile, DR cannot be explored as a completely separate component amid modern, well-integrated energy systems. That is why it is also important to investigate the coherence of DR with other smart solutions and technologies. The following are the main influencers of DR implementation and performance (Figure 4):
Figure 4. The Influencers of DR implementation and performance.
-
The type of pricing mechanism used can have a significant impact on DR participation. TOU pricing, which charges different rates for electricity at different times of the day, is one of the most common DR pricing mechanisms. Other pricing mechanisms include CPP, VPP, RTP
[38][39].
-
Incentives can be used to encourage consumers to participate in DR programs. These incentives can include cash payments, bill credits, or other rewards
[32].
-
The availability of technology can also influence DR implementation and performance. For example, smart meters can be used to track and manage energy consumption, which can make it easier for consumers to participate in DR programs
[40].
-
Government regulations can also influence DR implementation and performance. For example, some governments require utilities to offer DR programs to their customers
[32][41].
-
Customer awareness of DR programs is also important. If consumers are not aware of the benefits of DR, they are less likely to participate in those programs
[42].
By effectively considering these influencers, utilities and policymakers can design DR programs that are attractive and beneficial to both consumers and the overall energy system. Next, the research describes the implementation of each initiative, its barriers, enables and real examples.
For easier comprehension of further discussion, the authors introduce the summary of main enables and barriers of DR implementation and performance influencers (Table 1).
Table 1. Main enables and barriers of DR implementation and performance influencers.
Influencers
|
Enables
|
Barriers
|
Pricing
|
TOU
|
Understandable and straightforward implementation
|
Less effective in sharp peak curtailments
|
CPP
|
Effectively empowers grid stability
Additional revenue for utilities during peak periods
|
Poor management can result in lower participation level
|
VPP
|
Moderate stimulus for load shifting
|
Quite dynamic pricing signals
|
RTP
|
Electricity consumption optimization based on real-time market
|
Advanced information and communication infrastructure
|
Incentives
|
Financial rewards or other benefits for consumers
|
Financial resources for incentives from utilities and grid operators
|
Higher customer loyalty
|
Overcompensation risk
|
Promote environmentally friendly energy system and eco-friendly technologies
|
Budget constraints of utilities may limit incentives and lead to lower participation rates
|
Cost savings for utilities and grid operators
|
Complex and time-consuming administration
|
|
Technical requirements
|
Technology
|
Real-time monitoring and control
|
Upfront costs for utilities and consumers
|
Informed decision making
|
Privacy and security concerns
|
Faster, more precise responses
|
Digital divide between consumers
|
Optimized DR strategies
|
Complexity that requires technical expertise and trainings
|
Automated DR
|
Malfunctioning issues or lack of compatibility
|
Emergence of DR aggregators
|
|
Customer awareness
|
Familiarity and knowledge
|
Unfamiliarity and lack of knowledge
|
Social motivations
|
Distrust
|
Innovativeness
|
Technology requirements and technical issues
|
Financial and other benefits
|
Financial costs
|
Environmental motivations
|
Risks—finance, autonomy, comfort, adaptability
|
Reputation
|
|
Regulation
|
Financial incentives
|
Additional compliance (administrative, financial) costs for utilities and other stakeholders
|
Regulatory support
|
Complex and challenging compliance process
|
Promotion of technology adoption
|
Slow and changeable regulation
|
Standardization
|
Government-mandated DR programs may lack flexibility
|
Regulations and clear guidelines on data privacy and security
|
|
Empowerment of market competition
|
|
Transparent and fair regulations build trust and enhance participation rates
|
|