Submitted Successfully!
To reward your contribution, here is a gift for you: A free trial for our video production service.
Thank you for your contribution! You can also upload a video entry or images related to this topic.
Version Summary Created by Modification Content Size Created at Operation
1 -- 2906 2023-03-17 08:48:25 |
2 format correct Meta information modification 2906 2023-03-17 09:07:08 |

Video Upload Options

We provide professional Video Production Services to translate complex research into visually appealing presentations. Would you like to try it?

Confirm

Are you sure to Delete?
Cite
If you have any further questions, please contact Encyclopedia Editorial Office.
Mushafiq, M.; Arisar, M.M.K.; Tariq, H.; Czapp, S. Energy Efficiency and Economic Policy. Encyclopedia. Available online: https://encyclopedia.pub/entry/42296 (accessed on 22 December 2024).
Mushafiq M, Arisar MMK, Tariq H, Czapp S. Energy Efficiency and Economic Policy. Encyclopedia. Available at: https://encyclopedia.pub/entry/42296. Accessed December 22, 2024.
Mushafiq, Muhammad, Muzammil Muhammad Khan Arisar, Hanan Tariq, Stanislaw Czapp. "Energy Efficiency and Economic Policy" Encyclopedia, https://encyclopedia.pub/entry/42296 (accessed December 22, 2024).
Mushafiq, M., Arisar, M.M.K., Tariq, H., & Czapp, S. (2023, March 17). Energy Efficiency and Economic Policy. In Encyclopedia. https://encyclopedia.pub/entry/42296
Mushafiq, Muhammad, et al. "Energy Efficiency and Economic Policy." Encyclopedia. Web. 17 March, 2023.
Energy Efficiency and Economic Policy
Edit

Reduced energy consumption and emissions of greenhouse gases are the results of increased energy efficiency. Additionally, energy efficiency measures can also promote energy equity by improving the accessibility and affordability of energy services for low-income and marginalized communities, leading to positive economic outcomes. Increasing energy efficiency can be accomplished in several ways, for instance, through the adoption of more effective technology, the modification of existing building designs, and individual behavioral shifts. Energy efficiency is crucial since it has been shown to cut costs, decrease emissions of greenhouse gases, and improve environmental conditions. Energy efficiency lessens demands for fossil fuels and the emissions that come with them by cutting energy consumption. It also aids in the preservation of finite and more expensive to extract natural resources such as coal, oil, and natural gas. Energy efficiency can also lead to lower energy bills; boosting people’s disposable pay in this way can boost the economy and lead to more job opportunities. Public health can also benefit from energy efficiency since it lessens the need for energy infrastructure such as power plants and transmission lines, which in turn reduces air pollution.

energy efficiency economic policy incentives

1. Subsidies

Government subsidies are direct monetary payments made to energy-efficient individuals, organizations, and businesses. The fundamental purpose of subsidies is to decrease the cost of energy-efficient technologies, thus making them more accessible and affordable to consumers [1][2][3]. There are a variety of sorts of subsidies, such as grants, loans, tax benefits, etc. Frequently, subsidies are used to promote the development and implementation of renewable energy sources. Government subsidies may be available to companies that invest in renewable energy technology [4][5][6]. These subsidies can help reduce the cost of renewable energy systems and increase their competitiveness against conventional energy sources.
Subsidies can also be used to promote the adoption of energy-efficient appliances, cars, and structures. Individuals that purchase energy-efficient appliances or automobiles, as well as enterprises that invest in energy-efficient equipment, receive government incentives. These subsidies can assist in reducing the price of energy-efficient products, making them more accessible and affordable for customers. The United States is an example of a government that has offered incentives to consumers and companies purchasing energy-efficient equipment. The federal government provides a number of incentive schemes for energy-efficient behavior and investment. For instance, the Energy Star program offers tax incentives to people and businesses who invest in energy-efficient appliances and cars. Energy Star was established in 1992 and is administered by the United States Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) and the United States Department of Energy (DOE). The program gives tax credits for appliances, air conditioners, and light bulbs that satisfy specified energy-efficiency criteria. The tax credits are intended to reduce the price of energy-efficient goods and promote their widespread adoption [7][8][9].
Subsidies can help develop a market for energy-efficient products and services in addition to decreasing the price of energy-efficient technology. By providing financial incentives for energy-efficient behavior and investment, subsidies can encourage firms to develop and install energy-efficient technology and encourage consumers to adopt them [9][10][11]. Australia’s Renewable Energy Target (RET) program serves as a real-world example of incentives that encourage energy-efficient behavior and investment. The RET is a market-based system that offers businesses and people financial incentives to invest in renewable energy technologies, such as solar panels, wind turbines, and hydropower. Under the RET, firms that create renewable energy are compensated for each unit of renewable energy they generate [12][13][14][15].
Some interesting findings are reached, and some social phenomena are explicated rationally by [16] while exploring the energy efficiency subsidies under market power. Initially, a rise in total subsidies increases the number of subsidized businesses. In addition, fiercer competition increases the number of enterprises requiring subsidies. Thus, the number of supported companies is contingent upon the level of competition in this field. Second, output subsidies result in a larger consumer surplus and a smaller producer surplus than fixed subsidies. Consequently, consumers prefer output subsidies, whereas companies prefer fixed subsidies. Finally, output subsidies have a more positive influence on the environment and subsidize more businesses than fixed subsidies. Thus, the effects of production subsidies on the environment outweigh those of fixed subsidies. The abovementioned work supported production subsidies and demonstrated benefits based on the environmental and consumer surplus effects.
Many researchers have argued for housing and vehicular subsidies for energy efficiency. The paper [17] shows that subsidized properties are associated with higher energy consumption than comparable market-rate properties, and that, among subsidized housing schemes, public housing tends to be the most energy-intensive. Despite the potential for retrofitting multifamily homes and the associated cost, energy, and carbon emission reductions, regulatory restrictions limit investment and consumption decisions for subsidized properties. The authors of the paper [18] in their investigation uncovered strong relationships between the quantity of subsidies received per capita in districts and characteristics indicating territorial stability and social capital. There are considerable disparities in the rate of subsidy receipt between regions that are considered economically disadvantaged and where the danger of energy poverty is greater. While border communities in the eastern United States demonstrate an above-average usage of funding for the insulation of existing homes, persons in larger cities and their suburbs are more likely to use subsidies for a new home. The results imply that subsidies should be redistributed and targeted more precisely in accordance with the program’s stated goals.
As presented in [19], if the subsidy is insufficient, a low-cost firm may manufacture an uncertified product while a high-cost firm produces a certified product. Additionally, the government’s optimal endogenous subsidy scheme operates under three distinct objectives: minimizing total energy consumption, average energy consumption per product, and average energy consumption per unit of GDP. In order to minimize total energy consumption, it is sometimes ideal to induce the low-cost firm to make an uncertified product and the high-cost firm to produce a certified product.
From the perspective of vehicles, the author of [20] suggested that subsidies for electric cars should be reduced or eliminated, with a focus on rapid increases in the fuel efficiency of light-duty vehicles, which will have positive spillover effects on the final energy intensity of electric vehicles and mineral needs following a delayed market scale-up. The author of the paper [21] recommended, instead of subsidizing, mandating the early market uptake of plug-in hybrid electric vehicles (PHEVs) and hybrid electric vehicles (HEVs). Furthermore, it is added that a preferable plan would be to rapidly boost automotive fuel economy requirements to that which can be attained only with HEVs, with moderate support for PHEVs, followed by the support for energy-efficient PHEVs and/or battery electric vehicles (BEVs) if scientific advancements essential for century-scale sustainability are accomplished.
While exploring evidence from China, the authors of [22] discovered that government subsidies had a substantial crowding effect on the R&D intensity of new energy vehicle (NEV) companies. As government subsidies increase, the crowding impact progressively decreases. From the aspect of EU-27, the authors of [23] report that the results are very diverse, depending on the power mix of each nation analyzed, and they indicate that the proposed subsidies can create advantages for consumers in countries that employ the greatest renewable energy sources. Using recent experiences from Estonia, the authors of [24] evaluated the energy renovation subsidy program and found that the distribution of renovation subsidies is linked to geographic socio-economic metrics and that real estate value explains 40% of subsidy distribution differences across geographic areas.
The research of [25] examined how government subsidies for energy efficiency in residential buildings could be best distributed to achieve maximum cost savings. The case study of the Danish municipality of Lyngby-Taarbaek was discussed, revealing systemic bias in heat demand estimations, with the result that older homes were incorrectly assigned a higher heat need than they had. As a result of this bias, 39% of all CO2 emissions are improperly allocated, and 40% of all subsidies are skewed.
It is essential to realize that subsidies might sometimes have significant disadvantages. Subsidies, for instance, might distort market signals, resulting in inefficient resource allocation. Subsidies can also foster reliance on government assistance, which can lead to market instability if government policies are altered. Subsidies are routinely utilized as a policy instrument to improve energy efficiency despite these potential downsides. Subsidies can aid in reducing energy consumption, cutting greenhouse gas emissions, and conserving natural resources by lowering the cost of energy-efficient technology and promoting their adoption.

2. Tax Incentives

Tax incentives are a type of economic policy that is used to encourage energy efficiency by making it cheaper to act and invest in ways that use less energy [26]. Tax incentives work by giving people or businesses who invest in energy-efficient products, technologies, or ways of doing business tax breaks or lower taxes. Tax incentives can come in the form of tax credits, tax deductions, tax exemptions, or other types of tax relief [27][28]. Tax breaks are a common way to encourage people to use less energy because they are easy to set up and can be tailored to specific actions or investments. For example, tax incentives can be used to get people to buy appliances or cars that use less energy, or to get businesses to invest in equipment that uses less energy. Tax breaks may be directed towards encouraging modifications to buildings that can result in significant energy savings and reduced emissions of greenhouse gases [29].
Tax incentives confer a financial advantage to individuals or organizations that alter their energy usage patterns or invest in energy-efficient technologies. This provides an impetus for such entities to undertake sustainable energy practices that can contribute to a reduction in greenhouse gas emissions and environmental conservation. By making these actions and investments cheaper, tax incentives can get more people to use energy-efficient products and practices, which can help cut energy use and greenhouse gas emissions [30][31]. For instance, The Energy Efficient Homes Tax Credit works by giving people who make changes to their homes that save energy a tax credit. The tax credit pays for a portion of the cost of the upgrades, which helps to lower the total cost of the improvements. So, people who use the tax credit are more likely to put money into energy-efficient home improvements, which can help them use less energy and release less greenhouse gases. Another benefit of tax incentives is that they are usually easy to change or adjust to keep up with changes in the energy market or in technology. Tax breaks can be changed to reflect changes in the prices of energy-efficient products or to encourage the use of new technologies that use less energy [32].
In the paper [33], findings imply that incentives to promote the use of energy-efficient appliances may be cost-effective, but whether they are or not depends on the specific nation and the alternatives being considered. In Denmark and Italy, tax credits on boilers appear to be a cost-effective choice, whereas in France and Poland, subsidies on compact fluorescent lamp (CFLi) bulbs are cost-effective in terms of €/ton of carbon dioxide (CO2) abated. Comparing the subsidies to the energy tax choices, the authors discovered that most of the time, the energy tax is more cost-effective than the subsidies.
According to a study of the effectiveness of current and former energy efficiency tax incentives by [34], the 10% energy efficiency tax credits implemented in 1978 were ineffective at generating significant energy savings because they encouraged the same tried-and-true energy efficiency measures that many customers and companies were installing on their own, leading to high costs for “free riders” (consumers and businesses that would have installed the efficiency measures regardless of the tax credits). In addition, the tax incentive was insufficient to encourage new installations.
While exploring the role of tax incentives in encouraging energy efficiency, the research in [35] found that while tax incentives certainly play a part in decision making, other non-tax considerations affect South African enterprises’ decisions to engage in energy efficiency and/or renewable energy projects, according to the findings. These firms did not consider the present tax incentives to be useful or sufficiently motivating for them to alter their environmental practices.
Tax incentives to modernize the energy efficiency of housing in Spain were explored in [36]; their findings showed that a monetary approach to encouraging residential energy efficiency is advantageous. In this regard, it suggests adding an incentive to the personal income tax tied to an increase in the energy efficiency rating of homes. In addition, it proposes changes to the present laws governing tax advantages for the real estate tax and the tax on building, installations, and infrastructure work.
From the perspective of China’s value-added tax reform, the research in [37] indicated that the reform decreases enterprises’ coal intensity by around nine percent. After the reform, coal intensity decreased more for large-scale enterprises, firms in energy-intensive industries, and private firms. This policy reduces energy consumption by encouraging businesses to invest in fixed assets and increase output. Nonetheless, tax benefits are not without restrictions. One difficulty with tax incentives is that they can be difficult to comprehend and implement, especially for small enterprises and individuals unfamiliar with the tax system. In addition, tax incentives may be costly to execute and have a major impact on government finances if they are not carefully targeted [38]. To be efficient and to have the least possible impact on government finances, tax incentives must be properly developed and administered.

3. Market-Based Mechanisms

Market-based methods are economic programs that employ market forces to increase energy efficiency [39][40]. These strategies are designed to generate a market-driven incentive for individuals and organizations to adopt energy-efficient behaviors and invest in energy-efficient technology. Market-based strategies include white certificate emissions trading systems (cap-and-trade schemes), and renewable energy regulations, among others. Emissions trading systems, commonly referred to as cap-and-trade programs, function by placing a limit on the total quantity of greenhouse gas emissions that may be produced in a certain region or industry. Companies that release greenhouse gases are thus obliged to possess emissions permits, with each permit reflecting the authority to emit a particular quantity of greenhouse gases [41][42]. Creating a market for emissions reductions, firms that pollute less than their allowances may sell their unused allowances to enterprises that emit more than their limits [43][44]. This market-driven incentive encourages businesses to cut their emissions and adopt energy-efficient practices and technology, as doing so reduces their emissions and the number of permits they must hold [45][46].
Market-based mechanisms have been proposed as a policy tool to promote energy efficiency, and one such mechanism is the use of white certificates. White certificates are a type of tradable instrument that serve as evidence of energy savings achieved by organizations, and they can be traded on a market that creates a competitive environment that incentivizes organizations to reduce their energy usage and encourage energy efficiency [47][48]. The use of white certificates can create a competitive market that drives down the cost of energy efficiency investments and encourages the development of new energy-saving technologies, thus facilitating the transition towards a sustainable economy [49][50]. This market can help overcome barriers to energy efficiency investment, such as the high upfront cost of energy-saving investments and the difficulty of measuring energy savings accurately. By promoting investment in energy efficiency, white certificates can help reduce energy consumption, greenhouse gas emissions, and promote sustainable development. Overall, white certificates can be an effective policy tool for promoting energy efficiency and contributing to climate change mitigation efforts [51][52][53][54].
The European Union Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) is a cap-and-trade system covering over 11,000 power plants and industrial units in 31 nations. It was established in 2005 and is the largest carbon market in the world. The system imposes a limit on the total amount of greenhouse gas emissions that may be generated by covered facilities and allocates a limited number of permits, each reflecting the right to release a particular quantity of greenhouse gases. The EU ETS has successfully reduced greenhouse gas emissions in the electricity and industrial sectors and offered a market-driven incentive for businesses to adopt energy-efficient practices and technology [55][56][57].
Renewable energy requirements, also known as renewable portfolio standards, are an additional market-based mechanism that encourages energy efficiency. Electricity suppliers are required under renewable energy standards to generate a particular amount of their electricity from renewable energy sources. The EU’s Green Public Procurement (GPP) sets a criteria at 50 percent [58]. These criteria provide a market demand for renewable energy, which stimulates investment in renewable energy technologies and promotes the development and deployment of these technologies [59].
As a policy instrument for increasing energy efficiency, market-based methods provide several benefits. Individuals and corporations are incentivized by the market to adopt energy-efficient habits and invest in energy-efficient technologies. These strategies can be more successful and efficient than command-and-control rules since they rely on market forces to promote energy efficiency [60][61]. Second, market-based procedures are adaptable and simple to modify in response to changes in energy markets and technology [62][63]. For instance, emissions trading systems can be modified to reflect changes in the cost of emissions reductions or to adapt to alterations in the trend of greenhouse gas emissions. Lastly, market-based procedures can be cost-effective because they let people and enterprises select the most cost-effective means of reducing energy use and emissions.
Summarizing the research in market-based processes, these are essential and efficient instruments for increasing energy efficiency. These approaches can be more effective and efficient than classic command-and-control rules by generating a market-driven incentive for energy efficiency and employing market forces to promote energy efficiency. Moreover, market-based procedures are quickly adaptable to changes in energy markets and technology, making them an appropriate policy instrument for encouraging energy efficiency in a fast-changing energy landscape.

References

  1. Jaffe, A.B.; Newell, R.G.; Stavins, R.N. Energy-Efficient Technologies and Climate Change Policies: Issues and Evidence. SSRN Electron. J. 1999.
  2. Martinot, E.; Borg, N. Energy-efficient lighting programs: Experience and lessons from eight countries. Energy Policy 1998, 26, 1071–1081.
  3. Hua, L.; Wang, S. Antecedents of Consumers’ Intention to Purchase Energy-Efficient Appliances: An Empirical Study Based on the Technology Acceptance Model and Theory of Planned Behavior. Sustainability 2019, 11, 2994.
  4. Blum, N.U.; Sryantoro Wakeling, R.; Schmidt, T.S. Rural electrification through village grids—Assessing the cost competitiveness of isolated renewable energy technologies in Indonesia. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2013, 22, 482–496.
  5. Frondel, M.; Ritter, N.; Schmidt, C.M.; Vance, C. Economic impacts from the promotion of renewable energy technologies: The German experience. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 4048–4056.
  6. Menanteau, P.; Finon, D.; Lamy, M.L. Prices versus quantities: Choosing policies for promoting the development of renewable energy. Energy Policy 2003, 31, 799–812.
  7. Brown, R.; Webber, C.; Koomey, J.G. Status and future directions of the Energy Star program. Energy 2002, 27, 505–520.
  8. Boyd, G.; Dutrow, E.; Tunnessen, W. The evolution of the ENERGY STAR® energy performance indicator for benchmarking industrial plant manufacturing energy use. J. Clean. Prod. 2008, 16, 709–715.
  9. Yeatts, D.E.; Auden, D.; Cooksey, C.; Chen, C.F. A systematic review of strategies for overcoming the barriers to energy-efficient technologies in buildings. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2017, 32, 76–85.
  10. Thiruchelvam, M.; Kumar, S.; Visvanathan, C. Policy options to promote energy efficient and environmentally sound technologies in small- and medium-scale industries. Energy Policy 2003, 31, 977–987.
  11. Stieß, I.; Dunkelberg, E. Objectives, barriers and occasions for energy efficient refurbishment by private homeowners. J. Clean. Prod. 2013, 48, 250–259.
  12. Buckman, G.; Diesendorf, M. Design limitations in Australian renewable electricity policies. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 3365–3376.
  13. Nelson, T.; Nelson, J.; Ariyaratnam, J.; Camroux, S. An analysis of Australia’s large scale renewable energy target: Restoring market confidence. Energy Policy 2013, 62, 386–400.
  14. Martin, N.J.; Rice, J.L. Developing renewable energy supply in Queensland, Australia: A study of the barriers, targets, policies and actions. Renew. Energy 2012, 44, 119–127.
  15. Valentine, S. Braking wind in Australia: A critical evaluation of the renewable energy target. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 3668–3675.
  16. Nie, P.Y.; Wang, C.; Yang, Y.C. Comparison of energy efficiency subsidies under market power. Energy Policy 2017, 110, 144–149.
  17. Reina, V.J.; Kontokosta, C. Low hanging fruit? Regulations and energy efficiency in subsidized multifamily housing. Energy Policy 2017, 106, 505–513.
  18. Frantál, B.; Dvořák, P. Reducing energy poverty in deprived regions or supporting new developments in metropolitan suburbs? Regional differences in the use of subsidies for home energy efficiency renovations. Energy Policy 2022, 171, 113250.
  19. Huang, W.; Zhou, W.; Chen, J.; Chen, X. The government’s optimal subsidy scheme under Manufacturers’ competition of price and product energy efficiency. Omega 2019, 84, 70–101.
  20. Harvey, L.D.D. Rethinking electric vehicle subsidies, rediscovering energy efficiency. Energy Policy 2020, 146, 111760.
  21. Harvey, L.D.D. Cost and energy performance of advanced light duty vehicles: Implications for standards and subsidies. Energy Policy 2018, 114, 1–12.
  22. Jiang, C.; Zhang, Y.; Bu, M.; Liu, W. The Effectiveness of Government Subsidies on Manufacturing Innovation: Evidence from the New Energy Vehicle Industry in China. Sustainability 2018, 10, 1692.
  23. De Santis, M.; Silvestri, L.; Forcina, A. Promoting electric vehicle demand in Europe: Design of innovative electricity consumption simulator and subsidy strategies based on well-to-wheel analysis. Energy Convers. Manag. 2022, 270, 116279.
  24. Lihtmaa, L.; Hess, D.B.; Leetmaa, K. Intersection of the global climate agenda with regional development: Unequal distribution of energy efficiency-based renovation subsidies for apartment buildings. Energy Policy 2018, 119, 327–338.
  25. Siddique, M.B.; Bergaentzlé, C.; Gunkel, P.A. Fine-tuning energy efficiency subsidies allocation for maximum savings in residential buildings. Energy 2022, 258, 124810.
  26. Surrey, S.S. Tax Incentives as a Device for Implementing Government Policy: A Comparison with Direct Government Expenditures. Harv. Law Rev. 1970, 83, 705.
  27. Briant, A.; Lafourcade, M.; Schmutz, B. Can Tax Breaks Beat Geography? Lessons from the French Enterprise Zone Experience. Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy 2015, 7, 88–124.
  28. Batchelder, L.L.; Goldberg, F.T., Jr.; Orszag, P.R. Efficiency and Tax Incentives: The Case for Refundable Tax Credits on JSTOR. Stanf. Law Rev. 2006, 59, 23–76.
  29. Brown, M.A.; Southworth, F. Mitigating climate change through green buildings and smart growth. Environ. Plan. A 2008, 40, 653–675.
  30. Kaygusuz, K. Energy for sustainable development: A case of developing countries. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2012, 16, 1116–1126.
  31. Stevens, C. Linking sustainable consumption and production: The government role. Nat. Resour. Forum 2010, 34, 16–23.
  32. Alexander, M.M.; Sulkowski, A.J.; Wiggins, W.P. Sustainability & Tax Policy Fixing A Patchwork of Policies with a Coherent Federal FrameworK on JSTOR. Va. Environ. Law J. 2016, 35, 1–58.
  33. Markandya, A.; Ortiz, R.A.; Mudgal, S.; Tinetti, B. Analysis of tax incentives for energy-efficient durables in the EU. Energy Policy 2009, 37, 5662–5674.
  34. Nadel, S. Energy Efficiency Tax Incentives in the Context of Tax Reform; American Council for an Energy-Efficient Economy: Washington, DC, USA, 2012.
  35. Dippenaar, M. The role of tax incentives in encouraging energy efficiency in the largest listed South African businesses. S. Afr. J. Econ. Manag. Sci. 2018, 21, a1723.
  36. Villca-Pozo, M.; Gonzales-Bustos, J.P. Tax incentives to modernize the energy efficiency of the housing in Spain. Energy Policy 2019, 128, 530–538.
  37. Zhou, Q.; Li, T.; Gong, L. The effect of tax incentives on energy intensity: Evidence from China’s VAT reform. Energy Econ. 2022, 108, 105887.
  38. Bhandary, R.R.; Gallagher, K.S.; Zhang, F. Climate finance policy in practice: A review of the evidence. Clim. Policy 2021, 21, 529–545.
  39. Portney, P.R.; Stavins, R.N. Public Policies for Environmental Protection; Routledge: England, UK, 2010; pp. 1–294.
  40. Almeida, E.L.F. De Energy efficiency and the limits of market forces: The example of the electric motor market in France. Energy Policy 1998, 26, 643–653.
  41. Pranindita, N.; Sagala, S.; Samosir, A.; Anhorn, J.; Van Laere, A.K.; Zacepins, A.; Sainz, A.; Rutz, D.; Rosslee, D.; Kirchmeyr, F.; et al. Biogas Market in Indonesia: The Roles of Carbon Trading. In Proceedings of the 2021 3rd International Sustainability and Resilience Conference: Climate Change, Sakheer, Bahrain, 15–16 November 2021; Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers Inc.: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2021; pp. 199–204.
  42. Hashim, H.; Zubir, M.A.; Kamyab, H.; Zahran, M.F.I. Decarbonisation of the Industrial Sector Through Greenhouse Gas Mitigation, Offset, and Emission Trading Schemes. Chem. Eng. Trans. 2022, 97, 511–516.
  43. Chesney, M.; Taschini, L. The Endogenous Price Dynamics of Emission Allowances and an Application to CO 2 Option Pricing. Appl. Math. Financ. 2012, 19, 447–475.
  44. Zhao, X.; Shang, Y.; Ma, X.; Xia, P.; Shahzad, U. Does Carbon Trading Lead to Green Technology Innovation: Recent Evidence From Chinese Companies in Resource-Based Industries. IEEE Trans. Eng. Manag. 2022, 1–18.
  45. Voland, N.; Saad, M.M.; Eicker, U. Public Policy and Incentives for Socially Responsible New Business Models in Market-Driven Real Estate to Build Green Projects. Sustainability 2022, 14, 7071.
  46. Gou, Z.; Lau, S.S.Y.; Prasad, D. Market readiness and policy implications for green buildings: Case study from hong kong. J. Green Build. 2013, 8, 162–173.
  47. Zajkowski, K. Settlement of reactive power compensation in the light of white certificates. In Proceedings of the E3S Web of Conferences 19, UNSP 01037, Polanica Zdroj, Poland, 13–15 September 2017.
  48. Zajkowski, K. Determination of the Environmental Impact of Reactive Power Compensation in the Power GrID. Nonconv. Technol. Rev. 2016, 20, 54–61.
  49. Lo, K. A critical review of China’s rapidly developing renewable energy and energy efficiency policies. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2014, 29, 508–516.
  50. Mundaca, L. Markets for energy efficiency: Exploring the implications of an EU-wide ‘Tradable White Certificate’ scheme. Energy Econ. 2008, 30, 3016–3043.
  51. Peñasco, C.; Anadón, L.D.; Verdolini, E. Systematic review of the outcomes and trade-offs of ten types of decarbonization policy instruments. Nat. Clim. Chang. 2021, 11, 257–265.
  52. Giraudet, L.G.; Bodineau, L.; Finon, D. The costs and benefits of white certificates schemes. Energy Effic. 2012, 5, 179–199.
  53. Langniss, O.; Praetorius, B. How much market do market-based instruments create? An analysis for the case of “white” certificates. Energy Policy 2006, 34, 200–211.
  54. Parmentola, A.; Petrillo, A.; Tutore, I.; De Felice, F. Is blockchain able to enhance environmental sustainability? A systematic review and research agenda from the perspective of Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs). Bus. Strateg. Environ. 2022, 31, 194–217.
  55. Perino, G.; Willner, M.; Quemin, S.; Pahle, M. The European Union Emissions Trading System Market Stability Reserve: Does It Stabilize or Destabilize the Market? Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2022, 16, 338–345.
  56. Nguyen, M.A.T.; Yu, M.M.; Lirn, T.C. Airlines’ eco-productivity changes and the European Union Emissions Trading System. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2022, 102, 103100.
  57. Fageda, X.; Teixidó, J.J. Pricing carbon in the aviation sector: Evidence from the European emissions trading system. J. Environ. Econ. Manage. 2022, 111, 102591.
  58. EC Renewable Energy Directive. Available online: https://energy.ec.europa.eu/topics/renewable-energy/renewable-energy-directive-targets-and-rules/renewable-energy-directive_en (accessed on 5 February 2023).
  59. Zeng, L.; Du, W.; Zhang, W.; Zhao, L.; Wang, Z. An inter-provincial cooperation model under Renewable Portfolio Standard policy. Energy 2023, 269, 126771.
  60. Guo, R.; Yuan, Y. Different types of environmental regulations and heterogeneous influence on energy efficiency in the industrial sector: Evidence from Chinese provincial data. Energy Policy 2020, 145, 111747.
  61. Ngo, T.Q. How do environmental regulations affect carbon emission and energy efficiency patterns? A provincial-level analysis of Chinese energy-intensive industries. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2022, 29, 3446–3462.
  62. Wang, F.; Xu, H.; Xu, T.; Li, K.; Shafie-khah, M.; Catalão, J.P.S. The values of market-based demand response on improving power system reliability under extreme circumstances. Appl. Energy 2017, 193, 220–231.
  63. Papadaskalopoulos, D.; Strbac, G. Decentralized participation of flexible demand in electricity markets—Part I: Market mechanism. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2013, 28, 3658–3666.
More
Information
Subjects: Economics
Contributors MDPI registered users' name will be linked to their SciProfiles pages. To register with us, please refer to https://encyclopedia.pub/register : , , ,
View Times: 475
Revisions: 2 times (View History)
Update Date: 17 Mar 2023
1000/1000
Video Production Service