Anchoring: History
Please note this is an old version of this entry, which may differ significantly from the current revision.
Subjects: Economics
Contributor:

Anchoring or focalism is a cognitive bias where an individual depends too heavily on an initial piece of information offered (considered to be the "anchor") when making decisions. Anchoring occurs when, during decision making, an individual depends on an initial piece of information to make subsequent judgments. Those objects near the anchor tend to be assimilated toward it and those further away tend to be displaced in the other direction. Once the value of this anchor is set, all future negotiations, arguments, estimates, etc. are discussed in relation to the anchor. This bias occurs when interpreting future information using this anchor. For example, the initial price offered for a used car, set either before or at the start of negotiations, sets an arbitrary focal point for all following discussions. Prices discussed in negotiations that are lower than the anchor may seem reasonable, perhaps even cheap to the buyer, even if said prices are still relatively higher than the actual market value of the car. The original description of the anchoring effect came from psychophysics. When judging stimuli along a continuum, it was noticed that the first and last stimuli were used to compare the other stimuli (this is also referred to as "end anchoring". This was applied to attitudes by Sherif et al. in 1958 in their article "Assimilation and contrast effects of anchoring stimuli on judgments".

  • psychophysics
  • cognitive bias
  • anchoring effect

1. Adjustment Heuristic

Anchoring and adjustment is a psychological heuristic that influences the way people intuitively assess probabilities. According to this heuristic, people start with an implicitly suggested reference point (the "anchor") and make adjustments to it to reach their estimate. A person begins with a first approximation (anchor) and then makes incremental adjustments based on additional information. These adjustments are usually insufficient, giving the initial anchor a great deal of influence over future assessments.

Daniel Kahneman, one of the first researchers to study anchoring. https://handwiki.org/wiki/index.php?curid=1615460

The anchoring and adjustment heuristic was first theorized by Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman. In one of their first studies, participants were asked to compute, within 5 seconds, the product of the numbers one through eight, either as [math]\displaystyle{ 1 \times 2 \times 3 \times 4 \times 5 \times 6 \times 7 \times 8 }[/math] or reversed as [math]\displaystyle{ 8 \times 7 \times 6 \times 5 \times 4 \times 3 \times 2 \times 1 }[/math]. Because participants did not have enough time to calculate the full answer, they had to make an estimate after their first few multiplications. When these first multiplications gave a small answer – because the sequence started with small numbers – the median estimate was 512; when the sequence started with the larger numbers, the median estimate was 2,250. (The correct answer is 40,320.) In another study by Tversky and Kahneman, participants observed a roulette wheel that was predetermined to stop on either 10 or 65. Participants were then asked to guess the percentage of the United Nations that were African nations. Participants whose wheel stopped on 10 guessed lower values (25% on average) than participants whose wheel stopped at 65 (45% on average).[1] The pattern has held in other experiments for a wide variety of different subjects of estimation.

As a second example, in a study by Dan Ariely, an audience is first asked to write the last two digits of their social security number and consider whether they would pay this number of dollars for items whose value they did not know, such as wine, chocolate and computer equipment. They were then asked to bid for these items, with the result that the audience members with higher two-digit numbers would submit bids that were between 60 percent and 120 percent higher than those with the lower social security numbers, which had become their anchor.[2]

1.1. Difficulty of Avoiding

Various studies have shown that anchoring is very difficult to avoid. For example, in one study students were given anchors that were obviously wrong. They were asked whether Mahatma Gandhi died before or after age 9, or before or after age 140. Clearly neither of these anchors can be correct, but when the two groups were asked to suggest when they thought he had died, they guessed significantly differently (average age of 50 vs. average age of 67).[3]

Other studies have tried to eliminate anchoring much more directly. In a study exploring the causes and properties of anchoring, participants were exposed to an anchor and asked to guess how many physicians were listed in the local phone book. In addition, they were explicitly informed that anchoring would "contaminate" their responses, and that they should do their best to correct for that. A control group received no anchor and no explanation. Regardless of how they were informed and whether they were informed correctly, all of the experimental groups reported higher estimates than the control group. Thus, despite being expressly aware of the anchoring effect, participants were still unable to avoid it.[4] A later study found that even when offered monetary incentives, people are unable to effectively adjust from an anchor.[5]

2. Causes

Several theories have been put forth to explain what causes anchoring, and although some explanations are more popular than others, there is no consensus as to which is best.[6] In a study on possible causes of anchoring, two authors described anchoring as easy to demonstrate, but hard to explain.[3] At least one group of researchers has argued that multiple causes are at play, and that what is called "anchoring" is actually several different effects.[7]

2.1. Anchoring-and-Adjusting

In their original study, Tversky and Kahneman put forth a view later termed anchoring-as-adjustment. According to this theory, once an anchor is set, people adjust away from it to get to their final answer; however, they adjust insufficiently, resulting in their final guess being closer to the anchor than it would be otherwise.[8] Other researchers also found evidence supporting the anchoring-and-adjusting explanation.[9]

However, later researchers criticized this model, because it is only applicable when the initial anchor is outside the range of acceptable answers. To use an earlier example, since Mahatma Gandhi obviously did not die at age 9, then people will adjust from there. If a reasonable number were given, though, there would be no adjustment. Therefore, this theory cannot, according to its critics, explain the anchoring effect.[10]

Another study found that the anchoring effect holds even when the anchor is subliminal. According to Tversky and Kahneman's theory, this is impossible, since anchoring is only the result of conscious adjustment.[11] Because of arguments like these, anchoring-and-adjusting has fallen out of favor.

2.2. Selective Accessibility

In the same study that criticized anchoring-and-adjusting, the authors proposed an alternate explanation regarding selective accessibility, which is derived from a theory called "confirmatory hypothesis testing". In short, selective accessibility proposes that when given an anchor, a judge (i.e. a person making some judgment) will evaluate the hypothesis that the anchor is a suitable answer. Assuming it is not, the judge moves on to another guess, but not before accessing all the relevant attributes of the anchor itself. Then, when evaluating the new answer, the judge looks for ways in which it is similar to the anchor, resulting in the anchoring effect.[10] Various studies have found empirical support for this hypothesis.[12] This explanation assumes that the judge considers the anchor to be a plausible value so that it is not immediately rejected, which would preclude considering its relevant attributes. For example, an online-experiment showed that ratings of previous members of the crowd could act as an anchor. When displaying the results of previous ratings in the context of business model idea evaluation, people incorporate the displayed anchor into their own decision making process, leading to a decreasing variance of ratings. [13]


2.3. Attitude Change

More recently, a third explanation of anchoring has been proposed concerning attitude change. According to this theory, providing an anchor changes someone's attitudes to be more favorable to the particular attributes of that anchor, biasing future answers to have similar characteristics as the anchor. Leading proponents of this theory consider it to be an alternate explanation in line with prior research on anchoring-and-adjusting and selective accessibility.[14][15]

3. Influencing Factors

3.1. Mood

A wide range of research has linked sad or depressed moods with more extensive and accurate evaluation of problems.[16] As a result of this, earlier studies hypothesized that people with more depressed moods would tend to use anchoring less than those with happier moods. However, more recent studies have shown the opposite effect: sad people are more likely to use anchoring than people with happy or neutral mood.[17]

3.2. Experience

Early research found that experts (those with high knowledge, experience, or expertise in some field) were more resistant to the anchoring effect.[4] Since then, however, numerous studies have demonstrated that while experience can sometimes reduce the effect, even experts are susceptible to anchoring. In a study concerning the effects of anchoring on judicial decisions, researchers found that even experienced legal professionals were affected by anchoring. This remained true even when the anchors provided were arbitrary and unrelated to the case in question.[18]

3.3. Personality

Research has correlated susceptibility to anchoring with most of the Big Five personality traits. People high in agreeableness and conscientiousness are more likely to be affected by anchoring, while those high in extraversion are less likely to be affected.[19] Another study found that those high in openness to new experiences were more susceptible to the anchoring effect.[20]

3.4. Cognitive Ability

The impact of cognitive ability on anchoring is contested. A recent study on willingness to pay for consumer goods found that anchoring decreased in those with greater cognitive ability, though it did not disappear.[21] Another study, however, found that cognitive ability had no significant effect on how likely people were to use anchoring.[22]

4. In Negotiations

The term “anchoring” describes both a psychological-behavioural effect (known as the anchoring effect) as well as the tactical approach making use of this effect.[3][4] The anchoring effect is where we set our estimation for the true value of the item at hand.[1] In the negotiation process anchoring serves to determine an accepted starting point for the subsequent negotiations. As soon as one side states their first price offer, the (subjective) anchor is set. The counterbid (counter-anchor) is the second-anchor.[23]

In addition to the initial research conducted by Tversky and Kahneman, multiple other studies have shown that anchoring can greatly influence the estimated value of an object.[24] For instance, although negotiators can generally appraise an offer based on multiple characteristics, studies have shown that they tend to focus on only one aspect. In this way, a deliberate starting point can strongly affect the range of possible counteroffers.[8] The process of offer and counteroffer results in a mutually beneficial arrangement. However, multiple studies have shown that initial offers have a stronger influence on the outcome of negotiations than subsequent counteroffers.[25]

An example of the power of anchoring has been conducted during the Strategic Negotiation Process Workshops. During the workshop, a group of participants is divided into two sections: buyers and sellers. Each side receives identical information about the other party before going into a one-on-one negotiation. Following this exercise, both sides debrief about their experiences. The results show that where the participants anchor the negotiation had a significant effect on their success.[26]

Anchoring affects everyone, even people who are highly knowledgeable in a field. Northcraft and Neale conducted a study to measure the difference in the estimated value of a house between students and real-estate agents. In this experiment, both groups were shown a house and then given different listing prices. After making their offer, each group was then asked to discuss what factors influenced their decisions. In the follow-up interviews, the real-estate agents denied being influenced by the initial price, but the results showed that both groups were equally influenced by that anchor.[27]

Anchoring can have more subtle effects on negotiations as well. Janiszewski and Uy investigated the effects of precision of an anchor. Participants read an initial price for a beach house, then gave the price they thought it was worth. They received either a general, seemingly nonspecific anchor (e.g., $800,000) or a more precise and specific anchor (e.g., $799,800). Participants with a general anchor adjusted their estimate more than those given a precise anchor ($751,867 vs $784,671). The authors propose that this effect comes from difference in scale; in other words, the anchor affects not only the starting value, but also the starting scale. When given a general anchor of $20, people will adjust in large increments ($19, $21, etc.), but when given a more specific anchor like $19.85, people will adjust on a lower scale ($19.75, $19.95, etc.).[28] Thus, a more specific initial price will tend to result in a final price closer to the initial one.

As for the question of setting the first or second anchor, the party setting the second anchor has the advantage in that the counter-anchor determines the point midway between both anchors.[23] Due to a possible lack of knowledge the party setting the first anchor can also set it too low, i.e. against their own interests. Generally negotiators who set the first anchor also tend to be less satisfied with the negotiation outcome, than negotiators who set the counter-anchor.[29] This may be due to the regret or sense that they did not achieve or rather maximise the full potential of the negotiations. However, studies suggest that negotiators who set the first offer frequently achieve economically more advantageous results.[30]

The content is sourced from: https://handwiki.org/wiki/Philosophy:Anchoring

References

  1. Tversky, A.; Kahneman, D. (1974). "Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases". Science 185 (4157): 1124–1131. doi:10.1126/science.185.4157.1124. PMID 17835457. http://www.hss.caltech.edu/~camerer/Ec101/JudgementUncertainty.pdf. 
  2. Edward Teach, "Avoiding Decision Traps", CFO (1 June 2004). Retrieved 29 May 2007. http://www.cfo.com/article.cfm/3014027
  3. Strack, Fritz; Mussweiler, Thomas (1997). "Explaining the enigmatic anchoring effect: Mechanisms of selective accessibility.". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 73 (3): 437–446. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.73.3.437. https://semanticscholar.org/paper/bc4868d637b519e61a1a17749a5656b9df77cf02. 
  4. Wilson, Timothy D.; Houston, Christopher E.; Etling, Kathryn M.; Brekke, Nancy (1996). "A new look at anchoring effects: Basic anchoring and its antecedents.". Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 125 (4): 387–402. doi:10.1037/0096-3445.125.4.387.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1037%2F0096-3445.125.4.387
  5. Simmons, Joseph P.; LeBoeuf, Robyn A.; Nelson, Leif D. (2010). "The effect of accuracy motivation on anchoring and adjustment: Do people adjust from provided anchors?". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 99 (6): 917–932. doi:10.1037/a0021540. PMID 21114351. https://repository.upenn.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1375&context=marketing_papers. 
  6. Furnham, Adrian; Boo, Hua Chu (2011). "A literature review of the anchoring effect". The Journal of Socio-Economics 40 (1): 35–42. doi:10.1016/j.socec.2010.10.008.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1016%2Fj.socec.2010.10.008
  7. Epley, Nicholas; Gilovich, Thomas (2005). "When effortful thinking influences judgmental anchoring: differential effects of forewarning and incentives on self-generated and externally provided anchors". Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 18 (3): 199–212. doi:10.1002/bdm.495.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1002%2Fbdm.495
  8. Tversky, Amos; Kahneman, Daniel (1992). "Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty". Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5 (4): 297–323. doi:10.1007/BF00122574.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1007%2FBF00122574
  9. Epley, N.; Gilovich, T. (2001). "Putting Adjustment Back in the Anchoring and Adjustment Heuristic: Differential Processing of Self-Generated and Experimenter-Provided Anchors". Psychological Science 12 (5): 391–396. doi:10.1111/1467-9280.00372. PMID 11554672.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1111%2F1467-9280.00372
  10. Mussweiler, Thomas; Strack, Fritz (1999). "Hypothesis-Consistent Testing and Semantic Priming in the Anchoring Paradigm: A Selective Accessibility Model". Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 35 (2): 136–164. doi:10.1006/jesp.1998.1364. http://soco.uni-koeln.de/files/JESP35.pdf. Retrieved 2014-11-20. 
  11. Mussweiler, Thomas; Englich, Birte (2005). "Subliminal anchoring: Judgmental consequences and underlying mechanisms". Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 98 (2): 133–143. doi:10.1016/j.obhdp.2004.12.002.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1016%2Fj.obhdp.2004.12.002
  12. Chapman, Gretchen B.; Johnson, Eric J. (1999). "Anchoring, Activation, and the Construction of Values". Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 79 (2): 115–153. doi:10.1006/obhd.1999.2841. PMID 10433900.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1006%2Fobhd.1999.2841
  13. Goerzen, T.; Kundisch, D. (2017-12-10). "When in Doubt Follow the Crowd: How Idea Quality Moderates the Effect of an Anchor on Idea Evaluation". ICIS 2017 Proceedings. https://aisel.aisnet.org/icis2017/Peer-to-Peer/Presentations/7. 
  14. Wegener, Duane T.; Petty, Richard E.; Detweiler-Bedell, Brian T.; Jarvis, W.Blair G. (2001). "Implications of Attitude Change Theories for Numerical Anchoring: Anchor Plausibility and the Limits of Anchor Effectiveness". Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 37 (1): 62–69. doi:10.1006/jesp.2000.1431. https://semanticscholar.org/paper/740c691dcbd6ae32a6a39649ec2b96a2099828e0. 
  15. Blankenship, Kevin L.; Wegener, Duane T.; Petty, Richard E.; Detweiler-Bedell, Brian; Macy, Cheryl L. (2008). "Elaboration and consequences of anchored estimates: An attitudinal perspective on numerical anchoring". Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 44 (6): 1465–1476. doi:10.1016/j.jesp.2008.07.005.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1016%2Fj.jesp.2008.07.005
  16. Bodenhausen, G. V.; Gabriel, S.; Lineberger, M. (2000). "Sadness and Susceptibility to Judgmental Bias: The Case of Anchoring". Psychological Science 11 (4): 320–323. doi:10.1111/1467-9280.00263.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1111%2F1467-9280.00263
  17. Englich, B.; Soder, K. (2009). "Moody experts: How mood and expertise influence judgmental anchoring". Judgment and Decision Making 4: 41–50. 
  18. Englich, B.; Mussweiler, Thomas; Strack, Fritz (2006). "Playing Dice With Criminal Sentences: The Influence of Irrelevant Anchors on Experts' Judicial Decision Making". Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 32 (2): 188–200. doi:10.1177/0146167205282152. PMID 16382081.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1177%2F0146167205282152
  19. Eroglu, Cuneyt; Croxton, Keely L. (2010). "Biases in judgmental adjustments of statistical forecasts: The role of individual differences". International Journal of Forecasting 26 (1): 116–133. doi:10.1016/j.ijforecast.2009.02.005.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1016%2Fj.ijforecast.2009.02.005
  20. McElroy, T.; Dowd, K. (2007). "Susceptibility to anchoring effects: How openness-to-experience influences responses to anchoring cues". Judgment and Decision Making 2: 48–53. http://libres.uncg.edu/ir/asu/f/McElroy_Todd_2007_Susceptibility.pdf. 
  21. Bergman, Oscar; Ellingsen, Tore; Johannesson, Magnus; Svensson, Cicek (2010). "Anchoring and cognitive ability". Economics Letters 107 (1): 66–68. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2009.12.028.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1016%2Fj.econlet.2009.12.028
  22. Oechssler, Jörg; Roider, Andreas; Schmitz, Patrick W. (2009). "Cognitive abilities and behavioral biases". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 72 (1): 147–152. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2009.04.018. https://epub.uni-regensburg.de/21701/2/roder2.pdf. 
  23. Jung, Stefanie; Krebs, Peter (2019). The Essentials of Contract Negotiation. ISBN 9783030128661. https://books.google.com/books?id=A46dDwAAQBAJ&pg=PA28. 
  24. Orr, Dan; Guthrie, Chris (2006). "Anchoring, Information, Expertise, and Negotiation: New Insights from Meta-Analysis". Ohio State Journal on Dispute Resolution 21 (3). 
  25. Kristensen, Henrik; Gärling, Tommy (1997). "The Effects of Anchor Points and Reference Points on Negotiation Process and Outcome". Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 71 (1): 85–94. doi:10.1006/obhd.1997.2713.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1006%2Fobhd.1997.2713
  26. Dietmeyer, Brian (2004). Strategic Negotiation: A Breakthrough Four-Step Process for Effective Business Negotiation. Kaplan Publishing. ISBN 978-0-7931-8304-3. https://books.google.com/books?id=NcsUvgAACAAJ. 
  27. Northcraft, Gregory B; Neale, Margaret A (1987). "Experts, amateurs, and real estate: An anchoring-and-adjustment perspective on property pricing decisions". Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 39 (1): 84–97. doi:10.1016/0749-5978(87)90046-X.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1016%2F0749-5978%2887%2990046-X
  28. Janiszewski, Chris; Uy, Dan (2008). "Precision of the Anchor Influences the Amount of Adjustment". Psychological Science 19 (2): 121–127. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9280.2008.02057.x. PMID 18271859.  https://dx.doi.org/10.1111%2Fj.1467-9280.2008.02057.x
  29. Rosette, Ashleigh Shelby; Kopelman, Shirli; Abbott, Jeanna Lanza (2014). "Good Grief! Anxiety Sours the Economic Benefits of First Offers". Group Decision and Negotiation 23 (3): 629–647. doi:10.1007/s10726-013-9348-4. https://www.researchgate.net/publication/257567785. 
  30. Galinsky, Adam D.; Mussweiler, Thomas (2001). "First offers as anchors: The role of perspective-taking and negotiator focus". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 81 (4): 657–669. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.81.4.657. PMID 11642352. https://semanticscholar.org/paper/4593e56e2f94f5ffc75789ddacdfbe3670481cbe. 
More
This entry is offline, you can click here to edit this entry!
ScholarVision Creations